Jobs lost, jobs gained: What the future of work will mean for jobs, skills, and wages
Jobs lost, jobs gained: What the future of work will mean for jobs,
skills, and wages
November 2017 | Report
By James Manyika, Susan Lund, Michael
Chui, Jacques Bughin, Jonathan Woetzel, Parul Batra, Ryan Ko, and Saurabh
Sanghvi
In an era marked by rapid
advances in automation and artificial intelligence, new research assesses the
jobs lost and jobs gained under different scenarios through 2030.
The
technology-driven world in which we live is a world
filled with promise but also challenges. Cars that drive themselves, machines
that read X-rays, and algorithms that respond to customer-service inquiries are
all manifestations of powerful new forms of automation. Yet even as these
technologies increase productivity and improve our lives, their use will substitute
for some work activities humans currently perform—a development that
has sparked much public concern.Play Video
Powerful new technologies are
increasing productivity, improving lives, and reshaping our world. But what
happens to our jobs?
Building on our January 2017 report on automation,
McKinsey Global Institute’s latest report, Jobs
lost, jobs gained: Workforce transitions in a time of automation (PDF–5MB),
assesses the number and types of jobs that might be created under different
scenarios through 2030 and compares that to the jobs that could be lost to
automation.
The
results reveal a rich mosaic of potential shifts in occupations in the years
ahead, with important implications for workforce skills and wages. Our key
finding is that while there may be enough work to maintain full employment to
2030 under most scenarios, the transitions will be very challenging—matching or
even exceeding the scale of shifts out of agriculture and manufacturing we have
seen in the past.
We strive to provide individuals
with disabilities equal access to our website. If you would like information
about this content we will be happy to work with you. Please email us at: McKinsey_Website_Accessibility@mckinsey.com
1. What impact will automation have on
work?
We previously found that about half the activities people are
paid to do globally could
theoretically be automated using currently demonstrated technologies.
Very few occupations—less than 5 percent—consist of activities that can be
fully automated.
However,
in about 60 percent of occupations, at least one-third of the constituent
activities could be automated, implying substantial workplace transformations
and changes for all workers.
While
technical feasibility of automation is important, it is not the only factor
that will influence the pace and extent of automation adoption. Other factors
include the cost of developing and deploying automation solutions for specific
uses in the workplace, the labor-market dynamics (including quality and
quantity of labor and associated wages), the benefits of automation beyond
labor substitution, and regulatory and social acceptance.
Interactive
Taking these factors into account, our new research estimates
that between almost zero and 30 percent of the hours worked globally could be
automated by 2030, depending on the speed of adoption. We mainly use the
midpoint of our scenario range, which is automation of 15 percent of current
activities. Results differ
significantly by country, reflecting the mix of activities currently
performed by workers and prevailing wage rates.
The
potential impact
of automation on employment varies by occupation and sector (see
interactive above). Activities most susceptible to automation include physical ones
in predictable environments, such as operating machinery and preparing fast
food. Collecting and processing data are two other categories of activities
that increasingly can be done better and faster with machines. This could
displace large amounts of labor—for instance, in mortgage origination,
paralegal work, accounting, and back-office transaction processing.
It
is important to note, however, that even when some tasks are automated,
employment in those occupations may not decline but rather workers may perform
new tasks.
Automation
will have a lesser effect on jobs that involve managing people, applying
expertise, and social interactions, where machines are unable to match human
performance for now.
Jobs
in unpredictable environments—occupations such as gardeners, plumbers, or
providers of child- and eldercare—will also generally see less automation by
2030, because they are technically difficult to automate and often command
relatively lower wages, which makes automation a less attractive business proposition.
2. What are possible scenarios for employment growth?
Workers
displaced by automation are easily identified, while new jobs that are created
indirectly from technology are less visible and spread across different sectors
and geographies. We model some potential sources of new labor demand that may
spur job creation to 2030, even net of automation.
For the first three trends, we model only a trendline scenario
based on current spending and investment trends observed across countries.
Rising incomes and consumption, especially in emerging economies
We
have previously estimated that global
consumption could grow by $23 trillion between 2015 and 2030, and most of
this will come from the consuming classes in emerging economies. The effects of
these new consumers will be felt not just in the countries where the income is
generated but also in economies that export to these countries. Globally, we
estimate that 250 million to 280 million new jobs could be created from the
impact of rising incomes on consumer goods alone, with up to an additional 50
million to 85 million jobs generated from higher health and education spending.
Aging populations
By 2030, there will be at least 300
million more people aged 65 years and older than there were in 2014.
As people age, their spending patterns shift, with a pronounced increase in
spending on healthcare and other personal services. This will create
significant new demand for a range of occupations, including doctors, nurses,
and health technicians but also home-health aides, personal-care aides, and
nursing assistants in many countries. Globally, we estimate that healthcare and
related jobs from aging could grow by 50 million to 85 million by 2030.
Development and deployment of technology
Jobs related to developing and deploying new technologies may
also grow. Overall spending on technology could increase by more than 50
percent between 2015 and 2030. About half would be on information-technology
services. The number of people employed in these occupations is small compared
to those in healthcare or construction, but they are high-wage occupations. By
2030, we estimate that this trend could create 20 million to 50 million jobs
globally.
For
the next three trends, we model both a trendline scenario and a step-up
scenario that assumes additional investments in some areas, based on explicit
choices by governments, business leaders, and individuals to create additional
jobs.
Investments in infrastructure and buildings
Infrastructure and buildings are two areas of historic
underspending that may create significant additional labor demand if action is
taken to bridge
infrastructure gaps and overcome
housing shortages. New demand could be created for up to 80 million jobs in
the trendline scenario and, in the event of accelerated investment, up to 200
million more in the step-up scenario. These jobs include architects, engineers,
electricians, carpenters, and other skilled tradespeople, as well as
construction workers.
Investments in renewable energy, energy efficiency, and climate
adaptation
Investments
in renewable energy, such as wind and solar; energy-efficiency
technologies; and adaptation and mitigation of climate change may create new
demand for workers in a range of occupations, including manufacturing, construction,
and installation. These investments could create up to ten million new jobs in
the trendline scenario and up to ten million additional jobs globally in the
step-up scenario.
‘Marketization’ of previously unpaid domestic work
The last trend we consider is the potential to pay for services
that substitute for currently unpaid and primarily domestic work. This
so-called marketization of previously unpaid work is already prevalent in
advanced economies, and rising female workforce participation worldwide could
accelerate the trend. We estimate that this could create 50 million to 90
million jobs globally, mainly in occupations such as childcare, early-childhood
education, cleaning, cooking, and gardening.
When
we look at the net changes in job growth across all countries, the categories
with the highest percentage job growth net of automation include the following:
- healthcare providers
- professionals such
as engineers, scientists, accountants, and analysts
- IT professionals and
other technology specialists
- managers and
executives, whose work cannot easily be replaced by machines
- educators,
especially in emerging economies with young populations
- “creatives,” a small
but growing category of artists, performers, and entertainers who will be
in demand as rising incomes create more demand for leisure and recreation
- builders and related
professions, particularly in the scenario that involves higher investments
in infrastructure and buildings
- manual and service
jobs in unpredictable environments, such as home-health aides and
gardeners
Upcoming workforce transitions could
be very large
The changes in net occupational growth or decline imply that a
very large number of people may need to shift occupational categories and learn
new skills in the years ahead. The shift could be on a scale not seen since the
transition of the labor force out of agriculture in the early 1900s in the
United States and Europe, and more recently in in China.
Seventy-five million to 375 million
may need to switch occupational categories and learn new skills.
We estimate that between 400 million and 800 million individuals
could be displaced by automation and need to find new jobs by 2030 around the
world, based on our midpoint and earliest (that is, the most rapid) automation
adoption scenarios. New jobs will be available, based on our scenarios of
future labor demand and the net impact of automation, as described in the next
section.
However,
people will need to find their way into these jobs. Of the total displaced, 75
million to 375 million may need to switch occupational categories and learn new
skills, under our midpoint and earliest automation adoption scenarios; under
our trendline adoption scenario, however, this number would be very small—less
than 10 million
Exhibit 1
In absolute terms, China faces the largest number of workers
needing to switch occupations—up to 100 million if automation is adopted
rapidly, or 12 percent of the 2030 workforce. While that may seem like a large
number, it is relatively small compared with the tens of millions of Chinese
who have moved out of agriculture in the past 25 years.
For
advanced economies, the share of the workforce that may need to learn new
skills and find work in new occupations is much higher: up to one-third of the
2030 workforce in the United States and Germany, and nearly half in Japan.
3. Will there be enough work in the future?
Today there is a growing concern about whether there will be
enough jobs for workers, given potential automation. History
would suggest that such fears may be unfounded: over time, labor
markets adjust to changes in demand for workers from technological disruptions,
although at times with depressed real wages (Exhibit 2).
Exhibit 2
We address this question about the
future of work through two different sets of analyses: one based on modeling of
a limited number of catalysts of new labor demand and automation described
earlier, and one using a macroeconomic model of the economy that incorporates
the dynamic interactions among variables.
If history is any guide, we could also expect that 8 to 9
percent of 2030 labor demand will be in new types of occupations that have not
existed before.
Both
analyses lead us to conclude that, with sufficient economic growth, innovation,
and investment, there can be enough new job creation to offset the impact of
automation, although in some advanced economies additional investments will be
needed as per our step-up scenario to reduce the risk of job shortages.
A
larger challenge will be ensuring that workers
have the skills and support needed to transition to new jobs.
Countries that fail to manage this transition could see rising unemployment and
depressed wages.
The
magnitude of future job creation from the trends described previously and the
impact of automation on the workforce vary significantly by country, depending
on four factors.
Wage level
Higher wages make the business case for automation adoption
stronger. However, low-wage countries may be affected as well, if companies
adopt automation to boost quality, achieve tighter production control, move
production closer to end consumers in high-wage countries, or other benefits
beyond reducing labor costs.
Demand growth
Economic growth is essential for job creation; economies that
are stagnant or growing slowly create few if any net new jobs. Countries with
stronger economic and productivity growth and innovation will therefore be
expected to experience more new labor demand.
Demographics
Countries with a rapidly growing workforce, such as India, may
enjoy a “demographic dividend” that boosts GDP growth—if young people are employed.
Countries with a shrinking workforce, such as Japan, can expect lower future
GDP growth, derived only from productivity growth.
Mix of economic sectors and occupations
The automation potential for countries reflects the mix of
economic sectors and the mix of jobs within each sector. Japan, for example,
has a higher automation potential than the United States because the weight of
sectors that are highly automatable, such as manufacturing, is higher.
Automation will affect countries in different ways
The four factors just described combine to create different
outlooks for the future of work in each country (see interactive heat map).
Japan is rich, but its economy is projected to grow slowly to 2030. It faces
the combination of slower job creation coming from economic expansion and a
large share of work that can be automated as a result of high wages and the
structure of its economy.
Interactive
However, Japan will also see its workforce shrink by 2030 by
four million people. In the step-up scenario, and considering the jobs in new
occupations we cannot envision today, Japan’s net change in jobs could be
roughly in balance.
The
United States and Germany could also face significant workforce displacement
from automation by 2030, but their projected future growth—and hence new job
creation—is higher. The United States has a growing workforce, and in the
step-up scenario, with innovations leading to new types of occupations and
work, it is roughly in balance. Germany’s workforce will decline by three
million people by 2030, and it will have more than enough labor demand to
employ all its workers, even in the trendline scenario.
At
the other extreme is India: a fast-growing developing country with relatively
modest potential for automation over the next 15 years, reflecting low wage
rates. Our analysis finds that most occupational categories are projected to
grow in India, reflecting its potential for strong economic expansion.
However, India’s
labor force is expected to grow by 138 million people by 2030, or
about 30 percent. India could create enough new jobs to offset automation and
employ these new entrants by undertaking the investments in our step-up
scenario.
China
and Mexico have higher wages than India and so are likely to see more
automation. China is still projected to have robust economic growth and will
have a shrinking workforce; like Germany, China’s problem could be a shortage
of workers.
Mexico’s
projected rate of future economic expansion is more modest, and it could
benefit from the job creation in the step-up scenario plus innovation in new
occupations and activities to make full use of its workforce.
Displaced workers will need to be reemployed quickly to avoid
rising unemployment
To model the impact of automation on overall employment and
wages, we use a general equilibrium model that takes into account the economic
impacts of automation and dynamic interactions. Automation has at least three
distinct economic impacts. Most attention has been devoted to the potential
displacement of labor. But automation also may raise labor productivity: firms
adopt automation only when doing so enables them to produce more or
higher-quality output with the same or fewer inputs (including material,
energy, and labor inputs). The third impact is that automation adoption raises
investment in the economy, lifting short-term GDP growth. We model all three
effects. We also create different scenarios for how quickly displaced workers
find new employment, based on historical data.
The
results reveal that, in nearly all scenarios, the six countries that are the
focus of our report (China, Germany, India, Japan, Mexico, and the United
States) could expect to be at or very near full employment by 2030. However,
the model also illustrates the importance of reemploying displaced workers
quickly.
If
displaced workers are able to be reemployed within one year, our model shows
automation lifting the overall economy: full employment is maintained in both
the short and long term, wages grow faster than in the baseline model, and
productivity is higher.
However,
in scenarios in which some displaced workers take years to find new work,
unemployment rises in the short to medium term. The labor market adjusts over
time and unemployment falls—but with slower average wage growth. In these
scenarios, average wages end up lower in 2030 than in the baseline model, which
could dampen aggregate demand and long-term growth.
4. What will automation mean for skills and wages?
In general, the current educational requirements of the
occupations that may grow are higher than those for the jobs displaced by
automation. In advanced economies, occupations that currently require only a
secondary education or less see a net decline from automation, while those
occupations requiring college degrees and higher grow.
In
India and other emerging economies, we find higher labor demand for all
education levels, with the largest number of new jobs in occupations requiring
a secondary education, but the fastest rate of job growth will be for
occupations currently requiring a college or advanced degree.
Workers
of the future will spend more time on activities that machines are less capable
of, such as managing people, applying expertise, and communicating with others.
They will spend less time on predictable physical activities and on collecting
and processing data, where machines already exceed human performance. The
skills and capabilities required will also shift, requiring more social and
emotional skills and more advanced cognitive capabilities, such as logical
reasoning and creativity.Wages may stagnate or fall in declining occupations.
Although we do not model shifts in relative wages across occupations, the basic
economics of labor supply and demand suggests that this should be the case for
occupations in which labor demand declines.
Our analysis shows that most job growth in the United States and
other advanced economies will be in occupations currently at the high end of
the wage distribution. Some occupations that are currently low wage, such as
nursing assistants and teaching assistants, will also increase, while a wide
range of middle-income occupations will have the largest employment declines.
Income
polarization could continue. Policy choices such as increasing investments in
infrastructure, buildings, and energy transitions could help create additional
demand for middle-wage jobs such as construction workers in advanced economies.
The
wage-trend picture is quite different in emerging economies such as China and
India, where our scenarios show that middle-wage jobs such as retail
salespeople and teachers will grow the most as these economies develop. This
implies that their consuming class will continue to grow in the decades ahead.
5. How do we manage the upcoming workforce transitions?
The benefits
of artificial intelligence and automation to users and businesses, and
the economic growth that could come via their productivity contributions, are
compelling. They will not only contribute to dynamic economies that create jobs
but also help create the economic surpluses that will enable societies to
address the workforce transitions that will likely happen regardless.
Faced
with the scale of worker transitions we have described, one reaction could be
to try to slow the pace and scope of adoption in an attempt to preserve the
status quo. But this would be a mistake. Although slower adoption might limit
the scale of workforce transitions, it would curtail the contributions that
these technologies make to business dynamism and economic growth. We should
embrace these technologies but also address the workforce transitions and
challenges they bring. In many countries, this may require an initiative on the
scale of the Marshall Plan, involving sustained investment, new training
models, programs to ease worker transitions, income support, and collaboration
between the public and private sectors.
All societies will need to address four key areas.
Maintaining robust economic growth to support job creation
Sustaining robust aggregate demand growth is critical to support
new job creation, as is support for new business formation and innovation.
Fiscal and monetary policies that ensure sufficient aggregate demand, as well
as support for business investment and innovation, will be essential. Targeted
initiatives in certain sectors could also help, including, for example,
increasing investments in infrastructure and energy transitions.
Scaling and reimagining job retraining and workforce skills
development
Providing job retraining and enabling individuals to learn
marketable new skills throughout their lifetime will be a critical
challenge—and for some countries, the central challenge. Midcareer retraining
will become ever more important as the skill mix needed for a successful career
changes. Business can take a lead in some areas, including with on-the-job
training and providing opportunities to workers to upgrade their skills.
Improving business and labor-market dynamism, including mobility
Greater fluidity will be needed in the labor market to manage
the difficult transitions we anticipate. This includes restoring now-waning
labor mobility in advanced economies. Digital talent platforms can foster
fluidity, by matching workers and companies seeking their skills and by
providing a plethora of new work opportunities for those open to taking them.
Policy makers in countries with inflexible labor markets can learn from others
that have deregulated, such as Germany, which transformed its federal
unemployment agency into a powerful job-matching entity.
Providing income and transition support to workers
Income support and other forms of transition assistance to help
displaced workers find gainful employment will be essential. Beyond retraining,
a range of policies can help, including unemployment insurance, public
assistance in finding work, and portable benefits that follow workers between
jobs.
We
know from history that wages for many occupations can be depressed for some
time during workforce transitions. More permanent policies to supplement work
incomes might be needed to support aggregate demand and ensure societal
fairness. More comprehensive minimum-wage policies, universal basic income, or
wage gains tied to productivity
growth are all possible solutions being explored.
Policy
makers, business leaders, and individual workers all have constructive and
important roles to play in smoothing workforce transitions ahead. History shows
us that societies across the globe, when faced with monumental challenges,
often rise to the occasion for the well-being of their citizens.
Yet
over the past few decades, investments and policies to support the workforce
have eroded. Public spending on labor-force training and support has fallen in
most member countries of the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
Development (OECD). Educational models have not fundamentally changed in 100
years. It is now critical to reverse these trends, with governments making
workforce transitions and job creation a more urgent priority.
We will all need creative visions
for how our lives are organized and valued in the future, in a world where the
role and meaning of work start to shift.
Businesses
will be on the front lines of the workplace as it changes. This will require
them to both retool their business processes and reevaluate their talent
strategies and workforce needs, carefully considering which individuals are
needed, which can be redeployed to other jobs, and where new talent may be
required. Many companies are finding it is in their self-interest—as well as
part of their societal responsibility—to train and prepare workers for a new
world of work.
Individuals,
too, will need to be prepared for a rapidly evolving future of work. Acquiring
new skills that are in demand and resetting intuition about the world of work
will be critical for their own well-being. There will be demand for human
labor, but workers everywhere will need to rethink traditional notions of where
they work, how they work, and what talents and capabilities they bring to that
work.
Comments
Post a Comment